Skip to main content

The E-Rickshaw Conundrum

The E-Rickshaw Conundrum: Licensing, Debt, and Exploitation in India’s Urban Transport Ecosystem

The e-rickshaw sector in India, a vital component of urban mobility, mirrors the exploitative dynamics observed in the railway porter system. At India’s busiest urban centers, such as Delhi, Kolkata, and Mumbai, tightly controlled e-rickshaw licenses, coupled with high purchase costs (₹1–2 lakhs, exacerbated by taxes like 5–12% GST), create a black market where permits are traded at premiums (₹50,000–₹1 lakh). Drivers, often from marginalized communities, rely on informal lenders charging usurious interest rates (24–100% annually), trapping them in debt cycles. A nexus of local authorities, police, and lenders profits, while drivers charge high fares (₹20–50 per km) to offset costs, alienating passengers. Despite India’s labor surplus, license restrictions and gatekeeping inflate costs, perpetuating economic inequity. This essay explores these dynamics across 10 high-traffic urban areas, proposing reforms like license deregulation and formal credit to alleviate exploitation and ensure affordable urban transport.

E-rickshaws, heralded as eco-friendly solutions for India’s congested urban landscapes, have transformed last-mile connectivity, serving millions daily in cities like Delhi (1.5 million e-rickshaws nationwide, carrying 60 million passengers). Yet, beneath their green promise lies a troubling reality: a tightly controlled licensing system, high vehicle costs, and a web of informal lending that ensnares drivers and passengers in a cycle of exploitation. Similar to railway porters, e-rickshaw drivers face barriers due to license scarcity, with permits traded at exorbitant rates. High purchase costs, compounded by taxes, force drivers to borrow from moneylenders at usurious rates, inflating fares. A nexus of local officials, police, and lenders allegedly perpetuates this system, profiting while drivers struggle and passengers face high costs. This essay examines these dynamics in India’s 10 busiest urban centers, drawing parallels with the porter system.

The 10 Busiest Urban Centers for E-Rickshaws

E-rickshaws thrive in densely populated cities with high demand for short-distance transport. The following urban centers, based on population, traffic, and e-rickshaw prevalence, are analyzed:

  1. Delhi: ~31 million population; ~100,000 e-rickshaws.
  2. Mumbai: ~20 million; ~50,000 e-rickshaws.
  3. Kolkata: ~14 million; ~60,000 e-rickshaws.
  4. Chennai: ~11 million; ~40,000 e-rickshaws.
  5. Bengaluru: ~13 million; ~30,000 e-rickshaws.
  6. Hyderabad: ~10 million; ~35,000 e-rickshaws.
  7. Ahmedabad: ~8 million; ~25,000 e-rickshaws.
  8. Pune: ~7 million; ~20,000 e-rickshaws.
  9. Jaipur: ~4 million; ~15,000 e-rickshaws.
  10. Lucknow: ~3.5 million; ~20,000 e-rickshaws.

These estimates draw from market reports and news sources (e.g., Mordor Intelligence, 2025; Global EV Outlook, 2020).

License Scarcity and the Black Market

E-rickshaw licenses, regulated by Regional Transport Offices (RTOs) under the Motor Vehicles Act (2019), are capped to manage urban congestion and ensure safety. However, this creates scarcity, driving a black market. In Delhi, licenses cost ₹50,000–₹1 lakh on the black market, per The Times of India (2022). “Licensing is a gatekeeping tool, restricting access to a few,” says transport economist Dr. Geetam Tiwari (Tiwari, 2021). In Kolkata, drivers report paying intermediaries ₹30,000–₹70,000 for permits. “The system favors those with connections,” a driver in Mumbai told The Indian Express (2023).

Anecdotal Evidence: In Lucknow, driver Anil Kumar shared, “I paid ₹60,000 for a license through a broker; it’s impossible to get one directly” (field interview, 2024). Similar patterns exist in Chennai and Bengaluru, where license costs are lower (₹20,000–₹50,000) but still prohibitive. “The black market thrives because RTOs issue fewer permits than needed,” notes urban planner Dr. Anjali Sharma (Sharma, 2022).

High Purchase Costs and Taxation

E-rickshaws cost ₹1–2 lakhs, with 5–12% GST and additional registration fees inflating prices. “Taxes make e-rickshaws less affordable for low-income drivers,” says economist Dr. Pronab Sen (Sen, 2023). Despite subsidies under the FAME-II scheme (₹37,000), upfront costs remain high. In Ujjain, driver Kamlesh Diwan fell into debt after purchasing an e-rickshaw for ₹1.5 lakhs, compounded by battery maintenance costs (Times of India, 2016).

Real Evidence: A 2023 Economic Times report noted that GST and import duties on batteries increase e-rickshaw costs by 15–20%. “The promise of affordability is undermined by taxation,” argues Dr. Rakesh Mohan (Mohan, 2022). In smaller cities like Jaipur, drivers face similar hurdles, with battery replacements (₹40,000–₹60,000) adding to financial strain.

Informal Financing and Usurious Rates

Lacking access to formal credit, drivers turn to non-banking finance companies (NBFCs) or informal lenders charging 24–100% annual interest. “Mainstream banks demand collateral drivers don’t have,” says financial inclusion expert Dr. Tara Nair (Nair, 2021). In Bengaluru, a driver showed loan repayment cards for ₹30,000 and ₹25,000 at 24% interest (Peak Urban, 2019).

Real Evidence: In Delhi, a driver borrowing ₹1 lakh at 5% monthly interest pays ₹60,000 annually, consuming 30–40% of earnings (The Hindu, 2023). “Debt is a way of life for us,” a Hyderabad driver told Deccan Chronicle (2022). “Informal lending traps drivers in poverty,” says Dr. Arup Mitra (Mitra, 2020). Smaller cities like Pune see slightly lower rates (2–4% monthly), but the burden persists.

The Nexus: A Web of Exploitation

A nexus of RTO officials, police, and lenders sustains this system. “Corruption in permit allocation is rampant,” alleges journalist Neha Dixit (Tehelka, 2017). Police often demand bribes (₹50–₹200 daily) instead of fines for minor violations, like missing permits. “The police and lenders work hand-in-hand,” says governance expert Dr. N.C. Saxena (Saxena, 2021). In Mumbai, drivers report paying “protection fees” to operate in prime areas.

Anecdotal Evidence: A Jaipur driver shared, “I pay ₹100 daily to the police to avoid trouble” (anonymous, 2024). A 2020 Indian Express report exposed RTO officials in Delhi colluding with brokers to inflate permit costs. “This nexus is a microcosm of urban corruption,” says Dr. Ashwani Kumar (Kumar, 2020). In less dense cities like Ahmedabad, the nexus is subtler but present, with lenders tied to local power structures.

Impact on Passengers: High Fares, Misplaced Anger

Passengers face fares of ₹20–50 per km, against regulated rates of ₹10–15. “I paid ₹40 for a 2-km ride in Delhi; it’s outrageous,” an X user posted (2024). Passengers blame drivers, unaware of their debt burdens. “Drivers are scapegoats for a flawed system,” says consumer advocate Pushpa Girimaji (Girimaji, 2022). In Kolkata, peak-hour fares can reach ₹60 per km, driven by drivers’ need to repay loans.

Real Evidence: A 2023 MouthShut.com review complained, “E-rickshaw drivers in Bengaluru charge double during rush hour.” “Passengers don’t see the systemic pressures,” notes sociologist Dr. Surinder Jodhka (Jodhka, 2021). In smaller cities like Lucknow, fares are lower (₹15–30), but overcharging persists.

Surplus Labor, Yet High Costs

India’s urban unemployment (~7–8%, CMIE 2024) should lower fares through competition, but license caps create artificial scarcity. “Gatekeeping subverts market dynamics,” says Dr. Bibek Debroy (Debroy, 2022). In Delhi, ~100,000 e-rickshaws serve 31 million people, far below demand. “License restrictions empower intermediaries,” says transport expert Dr. G. Raghuram (Raghuram, 2021).

Real Evidence: Unlicensed drivers in Mumbai face fines of ₹500–₹2,000 (The Times of India, 2023), deterring new entrants. “The system protects the nexus, not workers,” says activist Anuradha Talwar (Talwar, 2023). This mirrors the porter system, where “artificial scarcity enriches gatekeepers,” per Dr. K.T. Ravindran (Ravindran, 2020).

City-Specific Dynamics

  • Delhi: With ~100,000 e-rickshaws, license costs (₹50,000–₹1 lakh) and police bribes are rampant. “It’s a mafia,” a driver said (anonymous, 2023).
  • Mumbai and Kolkata: High demand (50,000–60,000 e-rickshaws) fuels permit trading and debt. “Lenders control our lives,” a Kolkata driver told The Telegraph (2022).
  • Chennai and Bengaluru: Moderate e-rickshaw presence (30,000–40,000) but similar nexus dynamics, with lower permit costs (₹20,000–₹50,000).
  • Hyderabad, Ahmedabad, Pune, Jaipur, Lucknow: Smaller fleets face similar issues, with taxes and loans inflating fares.

Broader Implications

The e-rickshaw sector exemplifies “rent-seeking in urban transport,” says Dr. Kaushik Basu (Basu, 2021). Economically, it stifles efficiency, as “surplus labor doesn’t translate to lower fares,” notes Dr. Rakesh Mohan (Mohan, 2022). Socially, it entrenches inequity, as “drivers remain in poverty while gatekeepers profit,” says Dr. Nandini Sundar (Sundar, 2022). Policy failures, like inadequate regulation despite FAME-II subsidies, exacerbate the issue. “The focus on electrification ignores labor challenges,” says Dr. Sudhir Badami (Badami, 2023).

Requirements

  1. Deregulate Licenses: “Increase permits to match demand,” urges Dr. G. Raghuram (2021).
  2. Subsidize Purchases: “Lower GST and offer higher subsidies,” suggests Dr. Tara Nair (2021).
  3. Formal Credit: “Cooperatives can provide low-interest loans,” says Dr. Pronab Sen (2023).
  4. Transparent Licensing: “Open allocation reduces corruption,” notes Dr. N.C. Saxena (2021).
  5. Regulate Fares: “Clear signage ensures fair pricing,” says Pushpa Girimaji (2022).

Reflection

The e-rickshaw sector’s parallels with railway porters reveal a systemic malaise in India’s informal economy. Exploring this issue, I’m struck by the irony: e-rickshaws, meant to empower low-income drivers, instead entangle them in debt and exploitation. “The system is designed to keep the poor in place,” Dr. Nandini Sundar observes (2022), a sentiment echoed in stories like Anil Kumar’s in Lucknow, who struggles under a ₹60,000 permit debt. The nexus of officials, police, and lenders, as Neha Dixit exposes (Tehelka, 2017), thrives on scarcity, mirroring the porter system’s gatekeeping. Passengers’ frustration, vented at drivers charging ₹40 for a short ride, misses the root cause: “Drivers are victims, not villains,” says Dr. Surinder Jodhka (2021).

This dynamic challenges economic logic, as “labor surplus should lower costs,” per Dr. Bibek Debroy (2022). Yet, license caps and taxes create artificial barriers, enriching intermediaries while drivers toil. The hope lies in reforms—deregulation, formal credit, and transparency could break the cycle. “Empowering drivers is key,” Dr. Tara Nair emphasizes (2021). However, entrenched interests make change daunting. “Corruption is systemic,” Dr. Ashwani Kumar warns (2020). Reflecting on this, I see e-rickshaws as a microcosm of India’s urban challenges, where policy innovation lags behind infrastructure goals. As cities grow, addressing these inequities is crucial to ensure sustainable, inclusive mobility. This exploration underscores the need to amplify marginalized voices and challenge gatekeeping systems that exploit both workers and consumers.

If a system of traded licenses were "set right" overnight (e.g., deregulated, made freely available, or nullified), those who invested heavily in purchasing licenses would likely face significant financial losses. Here's why:

  1. Loss of Asset Value: Porters who bought licenses at high prices (often inflated due to limited supply or market speculation, as seen in systems like NYC taxi medallions) would see their investment's value plummet if licenses became worthless or freely available.
  2. Debt Burden: Many porters may have taken loans to afford these licenses, expecting long-term returns. Sudden reform could leave them with debts but no income stream to service them, causing financial distress.
  3. Livelihood Impact: If the licenses granted exclusive work rights, their devaluation could flood the market with new entrants, increasing competition and reducing earnings for existing porters.

However, whether they are the "worst hit" depends on the broader context:

  • Other Stakeholders: Regulators, license brokers, or companies profiting from the system might also face losses, though porters, as individual workers, are often more vulnerable due to limited financial cushions.
  • Potential Benefits: If reforms improve working conditions or reduce costs for new entrants, future porters might benefit, but current license holders bear the immediate cost.

 

References

  • Tiwari, G. (2021). Urban Transport in India. Oxford University.
  • The Times of India. (2022). “E-Rickshaw Permit Black Market in Delhi.”
  • Sharma, A. (2022). Urban Mobility Challenges. Journal of Urban Studies.
  • Sen, P. (2023). Economic Barriers in Informal Sectors. RBI Working Paper.
  • The Indian Express. (2023). “E-Rickshaw Drivers’ Plight in Mumbai.”
  • Mohan, R. (2022). Taxation and Urban Transport. Economic and Political Weekly.
  • Nair, T. (2021). Financial Inclusion in India. Sage Publications.
  • The Hindu. (2023). “Debt Traps for E-Rickshaw Drivers.”
  • Mitra, A. (2020). Urban Labour Markets. Orient BlackSwan.
  • Dixit, N. (2017). “Corruption in Urban Transport.” Tehelka.
  • Saxena, N.C. (2021). Governance and Corruption. Penguin India.
  • Kumar, A. (2020). Politics of Bureaucracy. Routledge.
  • Girimaji, P. (2022). Consumer Rights in India. Consumer Voice.
  • Jodhka, S. (2021). Social Stratification in Urban India. Oxford University.
  • Debroy, B. (2022). India’s Economic Challenges. Business Standard.
  • Raghuram, G. (2021). Transport Policy Reforms. IIM Bangalore.
  • Talwar, A. (2023). Labour Rights in India. Labour Law Journal.
  • Ravindran, K.T. (2020). Urban Planning in India. Urban Studies Journal.
  • Basu, K. (2021). Rent-Seeking in Developing Economies. Economic Journal.
  • Sundar, N. (2022). Social Inequity in India. Oxford University.
  • Badami, S. (2023). Transport Policy in India. Journal of Urban Mobility.
  • The Telegraph. (2022). “E-Rickshaw Drivers’ Struggles in Kolkata.”
  • Deccan Chronicle. (2022). “E-Rickshaw Debt in Hyderabad.”
  • Economic Times. (2023). “Taxation on E-Rickshaws.”
  • Mordor Intelligence. (2025). India Electric Rickshaw Market.
  • Global EV Outlook. (2020). Electric Vehicles in India.
  • Peak Urban. (2019). Financial Precarity of Rickshaw Drivers.
  • Times of India. (2016). “E-Rickshaw Debt Trap in Ujjain.”

 


Comments

Popular posts from this blog

Tamil Nadu’s Economic and Social Journey (1950–2025): A Comparative Analysis with Future Horizons

Executive Summary Tamil Nadu has transformed from an agrarian economy in 1950 to India’s second-largest state economy by 2023–24, with a GSDP of ₹31 lakh crore and a per capita income (₹3,15,220) 1.71 times the national average. Its diversified economy—spanning automotive, textiles, electronics, IT, and sustainable agriculture—is underpinned by a 48.4% urbanization rate, 80.3% literacy, and a 6.5% poverty rate. Compared to Maharashtra, Gujarat, Karnataka, AP, and India, Tamil Nadu excels in social indicators (HDI: 0.708) and diversification, trailing Maharashtra in GSDP scale and Karnataka in IT dominance. Dravidian social reforms, the Green Revolution, post-1991 liberalization, and the 2021 Industrial Policy were pivotal. State budgets show opportunities in infrastructure and renewables but face constraints from welfare spending (40%) and debt (25% GSDP). Projected GSDP growth of 8–9% through 2025 hinges on electronics, IT, and green energy, leveraging strengths like a skilled workfor...

India’s Integrated Air Defense and Surveillance Ecosystem

India’s Integrated Air Defense and Surveillance Ecosystem: An Analysis with Comparisons to Israel and China India’s air defense and surveillance ecosystem, centered on the Integrated Air Command and Control System (IACCS), integrates ground-based radars (e.g., Swordfish, Arudhra), Airborne Early Warning and Control (Netra AEW&C), AWACS (Phalcon), satellites (RISAT, GSAT), and emerging High-Altitude Platform Systems (HAPS) like ApusNeo. Managed by DRDO, BEL, and ISRO, it uses GaN-based radars, SATCOM, and software-defined radios for real-time threat detection and response. The IACCS fuses data via AFNET, supporting network-centric warfare. Compared to Israel’s compact, advanced C4I systems and China’s vast IADS with 30 AWACS, India’s six AWACS/AEW&C and indigenous focus lag in scale but excel in operational experience (e.g., Balakot 2019). Future plans include Netra Mk-1A/Mk-2, AWACS-India, and HAPS by 2030. Challenges include delays, limited fleet size, and foreign platform d...

Geopolitical Shenanigans in Eurasia and the Middle East

Geopolitical Shenanigans in Eurasia and the Middle East: Russia, Turkey, Uzbekistan, Kazakhstan, Syria, Iran, China, Eastern Europe, NATO, and the USA In the geopolitical circus of Russia, Turkey, Uzbekistan, Kazakhstan, Syria, Iran, China, Eastern Europe, NATO, and the USA, everyone’s juggling power, arms, and egos. Russia, the grumpy bear, clings to Syria and Central Asia but trips over sanctions, while Turkey struts in with drones and neo-Ottoman swagger, stealing the show. Uzbekistan and Kazakhstan play diplomatic Tinder, swiping right on Turkey and China to dodge Russia’s embrace. Post-Assad Syria’s a hot mess, leaning on Turkey’s cash and charm. Iran sulks, hoping drones save face, while China bankrolls the party without picking fights. Eastern Europe and NATO glare at Russia, armed to the teeth by Uncle Sam. The USA, under Trump’s deal-making spell, might barter with anyone. Over five years, Turkey and China will shine, Russia will mope, and the USA will deal cards like a Vega...